can ever the resource curse come to North Korea? - Marcus Noland, Andray Abrahamian, and DOng


North Korea’s Resource Headache
By Andray Abrahamian & Geoffrey See , May 1, 2012

(DO –

As Marcus Noland will make a point, to which I also agree, it was not a best choice of framework to see or analyze resource extraction, both current and potential, in the North thru the lens of resource curse.

It is because there is not really correlation, not to mention causation – resource curse by definition should involve correlation between the abundance of oil, gas and mineral resources and low economic growth and human development. The North was or still is said to be on the brink of collapse, lacking its ability to revive its economy and leaving its people starving, well before China looked to the natural resources the North is sitting. More to the point, such extraction will unlikely worsen the desperate food situation.  

In economic terms, the North, the author pointed out, has few of sellable products. Labor will remain cheap without regard to resource extraction.
In political terms, come on.
In social terms, to me, it is interesting. A more marketization will make the country more isolated. Though interesting, the discussion on resource curse does not usually include the issue of social terms.)  
     
(conclusion – the tapping of North Korea’s rich mineral and fossil fuel wealth, retards social change, as opposed to heralding some great reform. This paradox can be analyzed under the framework of resource curse)
North Korea’s moribund economy is one that most observers would like to see marketized and internationalized. This is often considered an end in itself, wherein such transformations would expose the country to irresistible forces of social and political reform. Indeed, there’s evidence that changes in 

(economic causes - Netherland)
The idea of a resource curse was developed in the 1980s, as economists noted that countries, particularly post-colonial ones, with large reserves of natural resources were often not developing as successfully as they potentially could. Sometimes, problems stem from economic causes, such as those faced by the Netherlands in the 1960s and ’70s, after huge reserves of natural gas were discovered in the North Sea. The export of this fossil fuel put tremendous strains on the economy’s manufactured goods, by driving up the exchange rate and making exports more expensive. Furthermore, human resources are drawn away from export-oriented industries, further eroding the competitiveness of the manufacturing sector. These economic pressures came to be known as “Dutch disease.”

(political causes- Nigeria)  
There are also political consequences associated with a resource boom. When there’s a lack of manufacturing to begin with, a country’s elites are incentivized to fight for control over the resource base, rather than producing wealth by other means. It’s easier for them to distribute resource wealth to secure their own positions and enrich their political alliesNigeria is an oft-cited example of this.

(going around resource curse – Norway)
Both the economic and political pressures brought by control of a valuable resource can be mitigated in a variety of ways, including good governance through strong institutions. Norway is an example, with its oil revenues parked in a sovereign wealth fund, which is only allowed to invest overseas. This prevents pork-barrel spending and limits the inflationary impact of resources.  Distribution of oil wealth is also heavily regulated.

(N. Korea is resource rich country, though no detailed info available about how rich it is)
North Korea, by all accounts, is rich in valuable natural resources, particularly coal, iron ore, gold ore, zinc ore, copper ore, limestone and graphite. North Korea is a statistics abyss, however, leaving a lot of guesswork for economists who keep an eye on the country. South Korea’s estimates put the North’s mineral resources figure at over $6 trillion.           

(Pyongyang boost efforts to bring in foreign investments)
There’s growing interest in exploiting these resources for export through joint ventures. There are more trade fairs in Pyongyang than ever before, and last autumn, Rason became the first city outside of the capital to host an international trade fair. North Korean investment officers we have worked with on economics and business training have been incredibly busy sending delegations out on investment roadshows, and two major organizations were set up in the last two years to bring in investments.

(Most of that foreign investment is Chinese; China’s ever-greater ownership of North Korean resources )
Most of that foreign investment is Chinese, of course, and Chinese companies have redoubled their focus on securing North Korea’s underground wealth over the last several years. For those willing and able to navigate a very trying business environment, the combination of cheap labor and accessible resources can potentially pay large dividends.

According to KOTRA, China’s trade with North Korea has tripled since 2005. Recent data suggests North Korea’s trade deficit with China has improved on the back of natural resources: A joint Yonhap-IBK Economic Research Institute study concluded that China imported 8.42 million tons of minerals from North Korea from January to September last year, worth $852 million. This was triple the amount imported during the same period of 2010.

(the North and the South, both are aware of China’s ever-greater ownership of North Korean resources, currently having no way out of it)
Some North Koreans have expressed wariness over the country’s increasing dependence on China. Nevertheless, since North Korea is unable to revive its transportation network, energy supplies, or manufacturing base on its own, the country appears to have little choice. Seoul, incidentally, is also concerned about China’s ever-greater ownership of North Korean resources, but not enough to overcome internal divisions over approaches to North Korea

(to reduce reliance on China, Pyongyang gives much authority to investment agencies to help reach out foreign capital)  
The new leadership recognizes that it can’t rely forever on exhortations to sacrifice for the stake of security and must find a way to deliver economic results. This requires foreign currency, and therefore sellable products, of which North Korea has few. North Korea’s growing interest in exploiting resources through joint ventures can be seen in the radically increased authority that investment agencies have been endowed with compared to their predecessors 3 to 4 years ago, as well as in the investment pitches they’ve made to investors abroad.

(ineffective, inefficient, and self-defeating internal competition for foreign investment)
New investment laws, whether well-drafted or not, and public pronouncements in favor of investments, whether supported by effective actions or not, make clear the government’s intentions. Over the last few years there have been multiple organizations competing for investments, suggesting a certain degree of competition at the apex of North Korean society. Cross-agency communication is notoriously bad in North Korea. Indeed, part of the country’s philosophy of centralized rule means that organizations share information upward, while remaining stovepiped from parallel organizations. Different investment agencies appear to have had different patrons and belong to different patronage networks. North Korean government officials have described the competition for investments as “intense.”

As many agencies take a cut of the investments they bring in, the blurred lines between profit-seeking and regulatory responsibilities, combined with some degree of competition with rival organizations, means that a development strategy based on foreign investments could degenerate into rent-seeking by rival patronage networks if the process is managed poorly.

(the two main agencies dealing with investment)
Recent reports from North Korea indicate that the two main agencies dealing with investment are in greater contact with each other. The Joint Venture and Investment Committee and the Daepung Investment Group operate under new investment laws passed in 2010 and amended in January this year. These laws are North Korea’s attempt to clarify the legal status of joint ventures along the lines of China’s own investment laws. Unifying competing institutions and revising legal codes are both positive signs.

(a lack of rule of law, property rights, transparency; commercial activities take place outside of the legal framework)
However, it remains to be seen how the relationship between JVIC and Daepung will develop. Discussions with North Koreans indicate that understanding of the rule of law and property rights remains weak, that transparency is a major issue, and that much commercial activity takes place outside of the legal framework put down on paper. This exposes business people without the right connections and backing to arbitrary penalties.    
   
(North Korea will struggle to avoid the trap, both in economic and political terms)
If managing resources and overcoming the so-called curse is a matter of concerted, institutional commitment and the corresponding development of effective economic institutions, North Korea will struggle to avoid the trap, both in economic and political terms. Pyongyang will increase trade and exports, but resources could go to supporting different – sometimes overlapping, sometimes competing – groups of elites. The issues with rule of law and competition at the top of society, combined with large payouts from mining joint ventures, could actually lead to a “resource-driven equilibrium.” Marketization without good governance could result in a stagnant and isolated economy, much like Burma over the last decade, as broad-based economic development is ignored while a narrow elite is enriched and existing power structures are strengthened by resource wealth.

We use the term marketization to mean both the reduction of controls over State-Owned Enterprises as well as a relaxation of restrictions on smaller business people or the informal markets. The commanding heights of the economy will be firmly in control of various groups of elites. Lower down, trade and market activity might be tolerated. Yet at the same time, the additional wealth at the top can be invested in apparatuses of control. While living standards will improve marginally, Burma’s situation over the past decade shows that this isn’t enough to sustain broad-base economic development.

(the third causes – in social terms.  Resource extraction involving a more marketized economy would leave the country more isolated)  
North Korea’s system has shown resilience to the encroachment of unofficial sources of news and information that have been growing since the mid-1990s. A more marketized economy with greater engagement with the outside world may allow more outside information in, yet paradoxically serve to bolster, rather than erode, this resilience. We might see a more internationally engaged economy, but one that’s still harnessed to maintain the social and political structures essentially as they are.

That marketization will naturally lead to other positive social and political changes in North Korea is too often assumed, and not questioned enough. Natural resources will provide more income for North Koreans. Nonetheless, we need to be prepared for the possibility that resource-fueled growth can lead to equilibrium where the economy is marketized, broader economic development remains a pipedream, and existing political structures that dominate North Korean society today are reinforced.

Andray Abrahamian is an Executive Director at Choson Exchange (www.chosonexchange.org), a Singapore-based non-profit focused on economics, business and legal knowledge exchange with North Koreans, and a lecturer at the University of Ulsan. Geoffrey See is a Managing Director of Choson Exchange.


The Resource Curse Comes to North Korea
by Marcus Noland           | May 17th, 2012

Roughly once every few months some news story or report crosses my desk touting the value of North Korea’s mineral deposits.  Back in 2009, the Swiss firm Quintermina stated that the country had the world’s second largest reserves of magnesite.  A Goldman Sachs report put the sub-soil riches in at $6trillion. Earlier this month it was the Choson Sinbo, perhaps not the most unbiased of sources, flogging North Korea’s mineral deposits.  Kim Jong-un got into the act, recently warning against “developing underground resources at random or creating disorder in their development.” And where mineral riches go, the resource curse is soon to follow. Andray Abrahamian and Geoffrey See should be credited with penning the first piece predicting its imminent arrival in North Korea.

I am tempted to dismiss all of this with “they wish.”  You see, to have a resource curse, well, you actually need commercially extractable resources, and while North Korea no doubt has a lot of resources in the ground, actual production has lagged.

So what exactly is the resource curse? In the 1950s, Argentinean economist Raul Prebisch argued that commodities were subject to a long-term secular decline in their terms of trade relative to manufactures. Post-colonial resource producers would be consigned to be the “hewers of wood and drawers of water” for the rich industrialized countries. Whether this hypothesis is correct is an empirical matter, and a quick glance at the gas pump, much less advanced statistical analysis, suggests that it probably is not.  Another possibility is that it is not the secular trend in prices that counts, it is the instability of export revenues that is the culprit, discouraging saving and investment, complicating macroeconomic policy management and generally encouraging a boom-bust mentality. Again, the statistical support for the proposition has been found wanting. Yet another possibility is the so-called the “Dutch disease” phenomenon. Named for the discovery of natural gas in the North Sea off the coast of the Netherlands in the 1970s, Dutch disease refers to the tendency of the real exchange rate to appreciate following the discovery of a valuable commodity or during commodity price booms rendering traditional industries internationally uncompetitive.  While Dutch disease complicates exchange rate management, it is unlikely to represent the whole explanation for the underperformance of commodity exporters, it is probably not the primary channel through which natural resource abundance could negatively affect economic performance. Rather, the primary channel through which resource endowments affect economic performance is through its impact on institutions and political development.

Resource producers tend to be undemocratic, though plenty of exceptions exist—Canada, Norway, and Botswana, just to name a few. In resource-abundant rentier states, the positive effect of high incomes on personal well-being has to be set against potentially destabilizing concerns about distribution: the absence of any transcendently rational or objective ground for determining who receives a share of the rents could potentially manifest itself in dissatisfaction. Authoritarianism may emerge as an understandable, though regrettable, response of a political leadership confronting a potentially aggrieved populace. The existence of rents can act as an emollient through multiple channels. The existence of rents may absolve governments from taxation and as a consequence relieve pressure for accountability. Rents may also furnish governments with revenues for patronage, often taking the form of generous public-sector employment. More subtly, commodity-derived rents can enable governments to co-opt social space, in effect creating oxymoronic state-sponsored non-governmental organizations (NGOs) and undercutting the formation of social groups genuinely autonomous of the state. A third channel through which rents may impede democracy would be by financing the development and maintenance of institutions of internal repression.

Symbiotically, the existence of commodity-derived rents increases the value of control of the state and intensifies incentives to contest political power. In the extreme, control of the resources themselves may fuel rebellion or prolong violent civil conflict, the most obvious examples being alluvial “conflict” or “blood” diamonds in the horrific civil wars of Sierra Leone and Liberia. More recently trade in “conflict minerals” such as tin, tantalite, tungsten, and gold, have been used to fund armed conflict in the Eastern Congo and surrounding regions. And while most contemporary examples of this phenomenon are found in sub-Saharan Africa, the problem is not limited to this region: it is claimed that illicit emerald mining, for instance, has helped finance the long insurgency in Colombia. Burma is another example.

So what does all of this mean for North Korea, at least potentially? It’s got plenty of problems with governance even without a resource windfall. The conventional wisdom is if a country has “good institutions” (e.g. Canada, Norway) when the resource riches begin rolling in, then the country can manage the windfall politically.  But if a country has weak or corrupt institutions, then the influx of resource wealth may actually worsen the situation socially and politically. Richard Pomfret has written an interesting paper on these issues as they relate to the countries of Central Asia, which with their Soviet legacies, may approximate North Korea in certain ways.  Those are not auspicious examples as Pomfret documents and the citizens of those countries can attest